Performance Pay: The Case Against

It’s our contention, nonetheless, that, in an ideal environment, commissions and bonuses are likely to be in conflict with the goal of the organisation.
 
June 15, 2008 - PRLog -- suggestions inflame passions faster than the suggestion that performance pay be abolished.

It’s our contention, nonetheless, that, in an ideal environment, commissions and bonuses are likely to be in conflict with the goal of the organisation.

Of course, traditional sales processes are not ’ideal environments’ and, as such, the traditional sales process serves as an illustration of the conditions under which performance pay is, in fact, appropriate!

Let’s begin, accordingly, with the case forperformance pay.

The case for performance pay
Let’s envisage a situation where performance pay definitely makes sense.

The situation that springsto mind immediately is outsourcing — or more generally — the use of contractors.

If you have outsourced a task to a contractor, it makes sense to compensate that contractor on a per-piece (or results) basis.

Because you are outsourcing, you have no control over the contractor’s production process (you can consider only inputsand outputs) and, as a consequence, it doesn’t make sense for you to gamble on something over which you have no control.

Most organisations understand this explicitly.  This is why most contractors (including service providers) are under pressure to quote on a fixed-price — rather than a time-and-materials — basis.

Now, if you consider the structure of a typical sales process (as discussed in the preceding article), you’ll realise that the relationship between the salesperson and the organisation is more similar to a contractor-clientthan it is to an employer-employee relationship:

1.
Salespeople are responsible for the end-to-end sales process.

2.
Management has limited (if any) access to objective process data.

3.
Salespeople perceive that they own customer relationships (and in many cases they do!)

In this environment, it certainly does make sense to pay salespeople as you would a contractor.

But, as you well know, we maintain that this isnot an ideal environment.

What we now have to consider is how the radically different environment we advocate impacts on the case for performance pay.

The ideal environment
In summary, the essential differences between a typical sales process, and the process we advocate are as follows:

1.
Salespeople are responsible only for the conduct of (sales) appointments.

2.
All other tasks (including the sequencing of salespeople’s appointments) are allocated to a sales support function.

3.
Sales process management decisions are subordinated to the organisation’s constraint.

If you consider the first two points above, it’s obvious that we are no longer outsourcing the sales process, in its totality, to the salesperson.

In fact, we have simplified the role of the salesperson to the point where he performs only one task (appointments*).  As well as increasing (massively) the productivity of the salesperson, the elimination of multitasking provides management with the ability to micro-manage the salesperson.

The thing is, if a salesperson performs one simple task, over and over, management now has access to a statistically relevant quantity of objective data.

This data-stream is the critical feedback loop that enables a process of continual improvement.

Now that the salesperson can be measured and managed intelligently, the case for performance pay is no stronger for the salesperson than it is for any (and every) other employee.

Which, of course, raises a very interesting question: wouldn’t it make sense to provide every employee with performance-based compensation?

Our consideration of point three (above) exposes the first of two fatal flaws in this common argument.

Fatal flaw one: the optimum is rarely the maximum
If you consider most performance-based compensation programs, their operation is simple.  Employees’ pay is linked (directly or indirectly) to their productivity.

Accordingly, the harder an employee works, the more he earns.

This approach assumes that incremental increases in employee productivity are necessarily good for the organisation.

Sadly, this assumption is dead wrong.  The fact is, in any process, incremental productivity improvements in only one resource will impact on that process’s output.  (This critical resource is the process constraint.)

Productivity improvements elsewhere will have either no positive impact, or even a negative impact, on process output.  (I’m referring now to non-constrained resources.)

Consider a simple organisational process consisting of the following sequence of activities (each performed by a separate resource):

1.
Promotion (the generation of sales opportunities).

2.
Sales (the conversion of sales opportunities to orders).

3.
Fulfilment (the fulfilment of these orders).

If you were managing this fictitious organisation, would you be likely to exhort the people responsible for these resources to produce at their maximum possible rates?

I hope not!

Presumably you’d recognise that there is no benefit in Promotion producing sales opportunities that Sales can’t process.  And, similarly, there’s no benefit in Sales generating orders that Fulfilment can’t fulfil.

To provide each of these individuals with a financial incentive to produce at maximum (individual) capacity will waste resources, unnecessarily inflate expenses, generate chaos and damage customer service.

It’s for this reason that the third attribute of an ideal environment (above) is that sales process management decisions are subordinated to the organisation’s constraint.

What this means is that the output of the various resources within our process should be synchronised with the maximum sustainable capacity of the process constraint.

Performance pay is likely to have the exact opposite effect.

Linking global rewards to global objectives
Now, if you think about it, the flawed assumption that incremental increases in employee productivity are necessarily good for the organisation does not have to ring the death knoll for performance pay.

It’s possible to envisage a compensation program that links local rewards to global optima.

For example, you could:

1.
Only reward team members at the process constraint for incremental increases in output.

2.
Compensate team members at non-constrained resources for maintaining optimal (rather than maximal) output.


Now, this (smarter) approach to performance pay overcomes the sub-optimisation* problem.  It does, however, introduce two questionable assumptions of its own — and it fails to address the second fatal flaw in the argument for performance pay!

Let’s consider the two assumptions first.

The first is that the process constraint will stay in the one location.  If it moves (and from time to time it will), it will be necessary to reconfigure your compensation program.  You will inevitably find yourself having to explain to team members at the prior constraint that they must now satisfy themselves with a lower rate of pay (this is particularly challenging when the team members involved are salespeople!).

The second assumption is that it is beneficial for team members at the constraint to strive for maximum output.  The reality is that what you want is not maximum output but maximum sustainable output.  While it sounds like a heroic endeavour, the pursuit of ’stretch goals’ increases volatility and decreases average output.*

It’s time now to unveil performance pay’s mostinsidious flaw: the assumption that pay drives performance.

Fatal flaw two: pay does not drive performance
At first glance, the assumption that people will work harder in the pursuit of a greater income looks innocent enough.

After all, a donkey will chase a carrot, won’t he?
End
Source: » Follow
Email:Contact Author
Zip:4122
Industry:Managment
Location:Brisbane - Queensland - Australia



Like PRLog?
9K2K1K
Click to Share